Running head: PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
1
Payroll Disparity Among Major League Baseball Teams:
Building a Competitive Team Despite Limited Resources
Sarah Holtschneider
A Senior Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment
of the requirements for graduation
in the Honors Program
Liberty University
Spring 2020
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
2
Acceptance of Senior Honors Thesis
This Senior Honors Thesis is accepted in partial
fulfillment of the requirements for graduation from the
Honors Program of Liberty University.
______________________________
Scott Ehrhorn, Ph.D.
Thesis Chair
______________________________
Tammy Brown, DBA
Committee Member
______________________________
David Schweitzer, Ph.D.
Assistant Honors Director
______________________________
Date
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
3
Abstract
There has been an inequality in payroll among Major League Baseball teams for many years that
became increasingly evident in the late 1990s. Revenue disparities among teams cause a
competitive imbalance for the league and make it harder for small-market teams to compete with
large-market teams with much higher payrolls. MLB has attempted to alleviate this disparity, but
the implementation of revenue sharing and the competitive balance tax alone is not enough for
small-market clubs to build a competitive team. There are a number of ways that small-market
clubs can build a competitive team despite limited resources, including employing the moneyball
hypothesis, quantifying market inefficiencies, utilizing the team’s farm system, taking advantage
of trade opportunities, and making intelligent contract decisions.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
4
Payroll Disparity Among Major League Baseball Teams:
Building a Competitive Team Despite Limited Resources
Introduction
There has been an inequality in payroll among Major League Baseball teams for many
years. Not only is there a disparity in payroll between separate teams, but there is also pay
variation among players on individual teams. The inequality in payroll among MLB teams and
players became increasingly apparent after the era of free agency, the formation of the Major
League Baseball Players’ Association (MLBPA), the strike of 1994, and the Curt Flood Act of
1998 (Grow, 2016; Krissoff, 2013). Studies have shown, as one would expect, that an individual
team’s payroll has a significant impact on that team’s success (Lu, Matthews, Wang, & Zhuang,
2018). In effect, this decreases the chances of small-market teams reaching and succeeding in
the postseason compared to larger-market teams and, therefore, causes a competitive imbalance
within the league. Relatively few fans want to see the same teams win the World Series year
after year, and no fans want to see their favorite team lose year after year, so MLB implemented
a revenue sharing program in an attempt to lessen the pay disparity among teams and improve
the competitive balance. While the plan does not make all teams equal, Rockerbie & Easton
(2018) found that revenue sharing produces significant utility gains at little cost. The agreement
intended to alleviate the growing inequalities found among large- and small-market teams and
improve the competitive balance within the league. Despite MLB’s implementation of revenue
sharing, payroll disparity and competitive imbalance are still present throughout the league.
While a team’s payroll has a significant impact on their performance relative to other teams, it is
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
5
not the only contributing factor to a team’s success. There are a number of ways that small-
market teams can build a competitive team despite their low budget.
Payroll Inequality Among Teams
The payroll inequality among teams has not always been as evident as it is today. The
valuation of MLB teams today ranges from $1 billion to $4.6 billion dollars, with twenty-two out
of thirty teams being valued at less than $2 billion, five teams being valued at $3 billion or more,
and only one team being valued at more than $4 billion: the New York Yankees at $4.6 billion
(“The Business of Baseball,” 2020). Four main occurrences contributed to the rise of player
salaries and the increasing disparity among team payrolls: the era of free agency, the formation
of the Major League Baseball Players’ Association (MLBPA), the strike of 1994, and the Curt
Flood Act of 1998. Lu et al. (2018) confirmed that when a team pays more to its players, it
enhances the team’s winning percentage. Similarly, organizations that compensate their
employees at higher levels than their competitors should expect to enjoy superior performance
(Hill, Aime, & Ridge, 2016). Having a higher payroll allows teams to offer star players higher
salaries, persuading them to sign with them rather than with a small-market team.
Free Agency
The minimum salary for MLB players in 2020 is $555,000 (MLB, n.d.). This means that
every MLB player is in the top one percent of American households (Krissoff, 2013). However,
this has not always been the case. It took lengthy and extended labor negotiations and the
emergence of new revenue sources for players to be able to make what they make today. In
1887, professional baseball owners added the reserve clause to contracts restricting their players
from signing contracts with new teams which limited players’ options to negotiate salaries in an
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
6
open market (Krissoff, 2013). This clause made it necessary for players to accept their team’s
salary offer, or to not play. It wasn’t until the 1970s that the reserve clause was altered. In 1972,
the Supreme Court ruled against Curt Flood in his bid to become a free agent, but in December
of 1975, a ruling by arbitrator Peter Seitz created the opportunity for players to move from one
team to another for the first time, and this ruling was subsequently upheld by the courts
(Krissoff, 2013). Though Curt Flood lost his bid for free agency at the time, he paved the way
for players to ultimately be granted free agency by transforming the reserve clause for future
players to have a say in what team they played for and how much they were paid.
MLBPA and the Strike of 1994
To offset the strength of team ownership, the Major League Baseball Players’
Association (MLBPA) was formed in 1954 (Krissoff, 2013). The negotiation of the first
Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA) between owners and the players’ association in 1968
increased the minimum salary for a Major League player as well as other necessities (Krissoff,
2013). Between 1972 and 1995, there were eight strikes and lock outs within the league. The
strike during the 1994-95 season lasted 232 days and was quite costly to both owners and
players. Following this strike, owners and players alike realized how high the cost of cancelling
games was and acknowledged the need for negotiation and agreement between them (Krissoff,
2013). In 1996, the minimum salary for a player was about $108,000, and the collective
bargaining agreement negotiated that year increased the minimum salary to $150,000 for 1997.
Since then, it has more than tripled to $555,000 (MLB, n.d.). The average salary had also tripled
between 1987 and 1997, from the $400,000 range to over $1.2 million, and it nearly tripled again
between 1997 and 2012 to over $3.3 million (Krissoff, 2013).
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
7
Curt Flood Act
Three Supreme Court decisions led to MLB’s exemption from antitrust laws with the
Court originally upholding in 1922 that professional baseball did not constitute interstate
commerce (Grow, 2016). This immunity to antitrust laws meant that players could not file
lawsuits against the league under antitrust laws. However, after the 1996 collective bargaining
agreement was approved, both sides agreed to jointly petition Congress to repeal baseball’s
antitrust exemption solely for purposes of allowing Major League players to file antitrust suits
against the league (Grow, 2016). The Curt Flood Act of 1998 allowed this and, therefore,
equalized the power between players and owners. Though the Curt Flood Act passed in 1998, it
started developing in the 1970s when Curt Flood lost his case for free agency. Shortly after his
case, in 1975, a ruling by arbitrator Peter Seitz granted Major League players the right to move
from one team to another for the first time (Krissoff, 2016). Knowing this ruling would soon be
granted, Andy Messersmith and Dave McNally opted to play the 1975 season without agreeing
to terms on a new contract with their teams for upcoming years. After the season, the two
claimed that the reserve clauses in their 1974 contracts only allowed their teams to claim their
services for one additional year (the 1975 season) and that they should be granted free agency so
they may sign with whichever club they choose (Grow, 2016). MLB attempted to dispute their
interpretation, but a panel of arbitrators ruled in favor of the players, and they were granted free
agency for the 1976 season (Grow, 2016). However, owners tried to take this right away from
them at every chance they could. In the 1985, 1986, and 1987 off-seasons, owners collectively
agreed amongst themselves that they would not bid on each other’s free agents. The MLBPA
then filed grievances charging the owners with collusion, and the owners settled these claims by
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
8
agreeing to pay the affected players $280 million in restitution (Grow, 2016). Over the next few
years, owners and the MLBPA continued to disagree and could not come to terms on a new
collective bargaining agreement before 1993. This is what triggered the strike of 1994 and
caused the league to cancel the World Series for the first time in 90 years (Grow, 2016). The
two sides finally reached an agreement in November of 1996 which included a provision
explaining that the Clubs and the MLBPA would work together to pass a law that would cover
MLB players under the antitrust laws giving them the same rights as other professional athletes
while the passage of the bill would not affect the antitrust laws in any other way (Grow, 2016).
This agreement is what eventually resulted in the passage of the Curt Flood Act in 1998.
Within Team Pay Inequality
While payroll inequality among teams seems to be the most evident factor in a team’s
performance, there have also been studies analyzing the correlation between intra-team payroll
and the team’s success. Today, player salaries range from the league minimum of $555,000 up
to $38.3 million (MLB, n.d.; Langs, 2019). Breunig, Garrett-Rumba, Jardin, & Rocaboy (2013)
found that there is a negative relationship between wage dispersion and overall team
performance. They concluded that increased wage dispersion leads to lower individual effort,
and consequently, lower team performance (Breunig et al., 2013). Their findings support the
theory that a small-market team with lower wage dispersion could perform better than a large-
market team with a high wage dispersion.
Tao, Chuang, & Lin (2016), tested whether the tournament theory or the cohesiveness
hypothesis is supported by the relation between salary dispersion and team performance. The
tournament theory suggests that employees’ efforts are dictated by the spread between the
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
9
earnings of each position, and the team-cohesiveness hypothesis suggests that narrow wage
differentials can improve cohesiveness and productivity in an organization (Tao et al., 2016). It
is common knowledge that players at different positions earn different salaries on all teams, so
the tournament theory would not be expected to have a large impact on team performance.
However, if players who make the minimum salary per year are performing well while their
teammates who make millions of dollars per year are underperforming, it is likely that the lower
paid players become unhappy with their salary. Tao et al. (2016) concluded that the team-
cohesiveness hypothesis is reasonable. The findings based on the team performance result
suggest that the team-cohesiveness hypothesis is supported over the tournament theory, but a
team’s payroll rank in MLB is still a stronger explanatory variable than a salary dispersion
variable is (Tao et al., 2016). Ultimately, the authors found that inter-team payroll disparity
contributes more to team performance than the structure of intra-team salary dispersion does
(Tao et al., 2016). However, small-market teams have little control over inter-team payroll
disparity while they have full control over the structure of their intra-team salary dispersion.
Small-market teams cannot simply increase their team payroll to $200 million to compete with
the Yankees, Dodgers, and Red Sox, but what they can do is minimize the intra-team salary
dispersion. Rather than compiling a team of mostly players that earn the minimum salary per
year and adding one or two all-stars that earn tens of millions of dollars per year, a team that
focuses on decreasing the range of individual player salaries would expect to perform better than
teams with high intra-team pay dispersion.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
10
Success of Small Market Teams versus Large Market Teams
The growing revenue and payroll inequities as well as the competitive imbalance between
teams became increasingly evident in the mid to late 1990s. In 1999, Commissioner Allan
“Bud” Selig assembled the Blue Ribbon Panel to study the effects this inequality had on
outcomes in MLB games, specifically postseason games (Hill & Jolly, 2015). The Panel divided
all teams into four quartiles based on the club’s payroll, with Quartile 1 consisting of the teams
with the highest payroll and Quartile 4 consisting of the teams with the lowest payroll. There
were 158 post-season games played during the 1995-1999 seasons, and no teams from the
bottom two quartiles won a post-season game during this period (Hill & Jolly, 2015).
Additionally, every team that won the World Series during each of those five seasons had a
payroll that fell into Quartile 1 (Hill & Jolly, 2015).
Between 2000 and 2019, this trend seemed to continue, though not as extreme. Many
more small-market teams made it to the postseason and won games, but the World Series
champions continued to be teams with high payrolls. Two out of the last twenty World Series
champions had the highest payroll in the league as of opening day (the 2000 New York Yankees
and the 2009 New York Yankees). Three more champions had the second highest payroll (the
Boston Red Sox in 2004, 2007 and 2018), and two more had the third highest payroll the year
they won it all (the 2013 Boston Red Sox and the 2019 Washington Nationals). Nineteen out of
these twenty champions had an opening day payroll that ranked in the top 50% of teams for that
season. Only one World Series champion between 2000 and 2019 had an opening day payroll in
the bottom 50% of payrolls: the 2003 Florida Marlins, whose payroll was ranked 25
th
out of 30
teams (USA Today, 2020).
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
11
MLB’s Attempt to Reduce Pay Inequality
As the payroll disparity became more and more evident within the league, MLB
attempted to lessen the disparity in two ways. The first, and more impactful, is the revenue
sharing program first implemented in 1996 that redistributes a percentage of local and national
revenues from large-market teams to small-market teams. The second is the competitive balance
tax, more commonly known as the luxury tax, which is similar to a salary cap such that it
penalizes teams for spending more than a certain amount on payroll for one year.
Revenue Sharing Program
The revenue sharing program used in MLB was first instituted in 1996 (Rockerbie &
Easton, 2018). Motivations for implementing a revenue sharing plan included supporting small
market teams, affecting league parity, suppressing player salaries, and improving team
profitability (Rockerbie & Easton, 2018). Small market teams struggle to compete with large
market teams when it comes to signing star players and winning championships. Revenue
sharing can also help suppress player salaries, and this is especially useful in MLB because the
league does not have a hard salary cap for its players or its teams.
The revenue sharing plan negotiated in the 2003-2006 collective bargaining agreement
increased the marginal tax rates associated with teams’ revenues from the 1997 collective
bargaining agreement levels which resulted in rates of 40% for high-revenue teams and 47% for
low-revenue teams (Hill & Jolly, 2015). Under the 1997 collective bargaining agreement, the
rates were 20% and 41% for high and low revenue teams, respectively (Hill & Jolly, 2015).
Owners and players agreed to these changes because they hoped it would increase competitive
balance on the field, but the changes did not have the intended effects. Some teams lowered
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
12
their payrolls to hold down costs which resulted in lower attendance and revenues and increased
the funds received through revenue sharing. Teams also divested their player talent and did not
compete rigorously in the talent market (Hill & Jolly, 2015). To remedy this situation, owners
and players agreed to a marginal tax rate of 31% for all teams in the collective bargaining
agreement covering the 2007-2011 seasons (Hill & Jolly, 2015). Jolly (2014) found that after the
2007 collective bargaining agreement, inequality among teams decreased, on average, indicating
that changes to revenue sharing should help increase competitive balance within the league.
Today, the league is under the 2017-2021 collective bargaining agreement which redistributes
48% of local revenues equally to all 30 MLB teams (MLB, n.d.). In 2018, each club received
$118 million from this, and teams also receive a portion of national revenues which were
estimated to be about $91 million for each team (Baseball Reference, 2020c). As total revenues
for MLB continue to grow, it is expected that each club will receive at least $209 million a year
from revenue sharing alone. This is a significant amount of money that small-market teams can
utilize to better their organization.
Competitive Balance Tax
Since the 1996 collective bargaining agreement, MLB has used a progressive competitive
balance tax (Rockerbie & Easton, 2018). This tax has become known as the luxury tax. For first
time offenders, if a team’s payroll exceeds the payroll threshold set in the most current collective
bargaining agreement ($206 million for the 2019 season), the team pays a tax rate of 22.5% of
the payroll overage (MLB, n.d.; Rockerbie & Easton, 2018). The tax rate increases every time a
team exceeds the threshold, to 30% for the second time, 40% for the third time, and 50% for four
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
13
or more offenses. It is estimated that the New York Yankees paid $304 million in tax over the
2002-2016 seasons (Rockerbie & Easton, 2018).
The competitive balance tax certainly discourages teams from utilizing high payrolls, but
as seen with the Yankees, it does not prevent it completely. The tax assists in keeping team
payrolls within a certain range, but the tax revenue is not redistributed to any MLB teams and,
therefore, lacks the redistributive component that the revenue sharing program implements.
Salary Cap and Salary Floor
While MLB does not have a salary cap, the competitive balance tax is viewed as a type of
salary cap by many baseball professionals, owners, and fans. There are two types of salary caps:
hard salary caps and soft salary caps. A hard salary cap prohibits teams from going over that
salary under any and all circumstances, such as in the NFL. A soft salary cap, which is what the
NBA has in place, allows teams to go over the set threshold but will penalize them in other ways
such as fines or a luxury tax. Even though the competitive balance tax in MLB is not called a
salary cap, it is very similar to a soft salary cap.
Implementing a hard salary cap is one way MLB could lessen the disparity among team
payrolls. The salary cap for NFL teams in 2019 was $188.2 million (Shook, 2019). The luxury
tax threshold in 2019 was $206 million and will increase to $208 million in 2020 (MLB, n.d.). It
is hard to imagine the league implementing a hard salary cap that is below the current luxury tax
threshold, but even if they set a hard cap at the current luxury tax threshold, it would prevent
teams from going over the threshold. However, with the MLB’s historic opposition to having a
salary cap, and with the soaring revenues that the league is seeing today, the league as well as the
MLBPA would likely reject implementing one now. Because of this, an alternative route that the
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
14
league could choose to go would be to implement a salary floor. A salary floor would require
teams to spend a minimum amount on payroll every year. As discussed earlier, every team
received over $200 million in 2018 from the revenue sharing redistribution system (Baseball
Reference, 2020c). Still, there are teams that have a payroll of far less than these amounts.
While not all of this can go straight toward player payroll for every team, much of it can. Team
payrolls for 2019 ranged from $53.5 million to $211.5 million; a difference of $158 million
(USA Today, 2020). Implementing a salary floor of $75 million or even $100 million would
decrease the payroll disparity and improve competitive balance. A salary floor, and what it
should be set at, could be discussed for the next collective bargaining agreement that will need to
be renewed in 2022.
Seeing inequality in payrolls within MLB seems to be inevitable today and will most
likely continue to be a problem for many years to come. Factors that contributed to growing the
disparity in the league included the era of free agency, the formation of the MLBPA, the strike of
1994, and the Curt Flood Act of 1998. The affect pay inequality had on the competitive balance
within the league became increasingly evident in the 1990s when no lower payroll team won a
single postseason matchup during the 1995-1999 seasons, and this competitive imbalance due to
payroll inequality has still been apparent over the last twenty years and today. MLB has
recognized this disparity and has taken steps towards diminishing the payroll inequality and
competitive imbalance within the league by implementing a revenue sharing program and a
competitive balance tax threshold. Though these undertakings have had a positive affect for the
league as a whole, pay inequality still seems to be the main factor that contributes to the
competitive imbalance we continue to see in the league. Small market teams must learn how to
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
15
utilize the revenue sharing program to their benefit, find ways to increase their revenue on their
own, and introduce new ways of building a competitive team without the financial resources
typically necessary.
Building a Competitive Team Despite a Small Budget
Lu et al. (2018) confirmed that when a team pays more to its players, it enhances the
team’s winning percentage. While a team’s payroll has a significant impact on their
performance relative to other teams, it is not the only contributing factor to a team’s success.
There are a number of ways that small-market teams can build a competitive team despite their
low budget. These strategies include employing the moneyball hypothesis, quantifying market
inefficiencies, utilizing the team’s farm system, taking advantage of trade opportunities, and
making intelligent contract decisions. Further research will analyze the moneyball approach,
along with other approaches and theories, in order to determine optimal strategies that small-
market teams can utilize in order to compete in an imbalanced league.
Moneyball Hypothesis
In order for small-market teams to compete with large-market teams, they must use a
different approach. Where large-market teams can simply sign big name players to enormous
contracts, small-market teams have to act differently. A well-known approach small-market
teams can take is known as the moneyball approach, which was first articulated by Lewis (2003)
in his book titled, Moneyball. The moneyball approach shows how a competitive team can be
assembled, despite a team’s small budget, by using an analytical, evidence-based, sabermetric
approach (Lewis, 2003). Sabermetrics, named after the Society for American Baseball Research
(SABR), is a way of analyzing baseball statistics in order to evaluate individual player
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
16
performance. This approach, first used by Oakland Athletics’ GM Billy Beane and his assistant
Paul DePodesta led the Oakland Athletics to high winning percentages despite the team’s low
payroll by analyzing statistics about a player’s walks and on-base average, rather than what
traditional baseball scouts could see with their own eyes. Small-market teams can only afford
one-tool players. According to the moneyball approach, the most efficient way to spend money
on baseball players is to spend it on hitters (Lewis, 2003). Eric Walker (as cited in Lewis, 2003),
a former aerospace engineer turned baseball writer, wrote that fielding was “at most five percent
of the game (Lewis, 2003, p. 58). The rest was pitching and offense (Lewis, 2003). At the
time, good pitchers were usually valued properly while good batters were not. Lewis (2003) cited
Walker as having stated, “[The] most critical number in all of baseball is 3: the three outs that
define an inning. Until the third out, anything is possible; after it, nothing is” (p. 58). He went
on to explain that the goal of an offense is to decrease its chances of making an out and that on-
base percentage is an isolated, one-dimensional offensive statistic that measures exactly that: the
probability that the batter will not make an out and will not put the team closer to the end of the
inning (Lewis, 2003). This simple observation was overlooked by almost all general managers
in MLB at this time. GM’s also tended to overvalue RBIs, the runs batted in statistic. RBIs were
treated as an individual achievement. However, in order to hit runners in, there must be runners
on base when a player comes to bat. A player’s ability to hit base runners in and receive credit
for an RBI, is heavily based on the achievement of others and/or luck. Bill James, an American
baseball writer and statistician, explained that the RBI statistic, among other baseball statistics,
“are not pure accomplishments of men against other men,” but “they are accomplishments of
men in combination with their circumstances” (Lewis, 2003, p. 71). General managers in MLB
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
17
during this time overvalued a player’s batting average and RBIs and undervalued a player’s on-
base percentage and slugging percentage.
According to Lewis (2003), James also observed that a hitter should be measured by his
success in creating runs. James disputed the belief that the purpose of an offense is to compile a
high batting average by stating that the purpose of an offense is actually to score runs. He
explained that the number of runs a player creates cannot be directly measured, but the number
of runs a team creates can be. James built a model to predict how many runs a team would score
given its number of hits, walks, stolen bases, etc. He achieved this essentially by predicting the
past. Using the statistics of the 1975 Red Sox, he determined the relative importance of what
players did at the plate and on the base paths to the team’s scoring patterns and assigning weights
to outs, walks, steals, singles, doubles, etc. The first version of what James called the Runs
Created formula is as follows:
Runs Created = (Hits + Walks) Total Bases / (At Bats + Walks)
The accuracy of this equation revealed that baseball professionals, owners, and general
managers did not place enough value on walks and extra base hits, which are featured
prominently in the Runs Created model, and placed too much value on batting average and stolen
bases, which are not even included in the model (Lewis, 2003).
The essence of the moneyball hypothesis is that the ability to get on base was
undervalued in the baseball labor market. Hakes and Sauer (2006) used linear regression
analysis to demonstrate that on-base percentage is a powerful indicator of how much a batter
contributes to winning games. The results of their analysis confirmed that there is a high
correlation between runs scored and linear combinations of on-base and slugging percentage.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
18
Looking at a team’s on-base percentage and slugging percentage compared to their opponent’s
on-base percentage and slugging percentage, can explain 88.5% of the variation in winning
percentage (Hakes & Sauer, 2006).
Quantifying Market Inefficiencies
The duo also advocated that an efficient labor market for baseball players would reward
on-base percentage and slugging percentage in the same proportions that those statistics
contribute to winning games. They found that the incremental salary impact for one-standard
deviation increase for slugging percentage in the first four years (2000-2003) increases from
$0.52 million to $0.70 million, and they are three to four times as large as the incremental impact
of a standard deviation increase in on-base percentage which only increases from $0.14 million
to $0.19 million (Hakes & Sauer, 2006). However, in 2004, the duo found that the value of one-
standard-deviation increase in on-base percentage increased to $0.49 million likely due to
Lewis’s publication of Moneyball in 2003 (Hakes & Sauer, 2006). The authors explained, “The
lack of a market premium for hitters with superior skill at the patient art of reaching base through
walks validates the systematic approach taken by the Oakland Athletics in identifying such
players, and thereby winning games at a discount relative to their competition” (Hakes & Sauer,
2006, p. 179).
Though Hakes and Sauer (2016) suggested that market inefficiencies have corrected
since the publication of Moneyball, Baumer and Zimbalist (2014) refuted that the relationship
between team payroll and performance has tightened since the publication of Moneyball.
Baumer and Zimbalist (2014) used official payroll data from the Labor Relations Department
(LRD) of MLB to determine that while the predictive power of payroll on winning percentage
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
19
was higher than it was in the 1980s and early 1990s, it was much lower in the 2000s than it was
in the late 1990s (Baumer & Zimbalist, 2014).
Farrar and Bruggink (2011) also used the moneyball approach to show that MLB general
managers do not reward hitters in a manner reflecting the relative importance of on-base
percentage and slugging percentage. The two developed a team run production model and a
player salary model to determine how an increase in on-base percentage and slugging percentage
increases salary (Farrar & Bruggink, 2011). They found that a 10 unit increase in team on-base
percentage brings in an additional 28.5 runs, and a 10 unit increase in team slugging percentage
results in an additional 17.4 runs (Farrar & Bruggink, 2011). The player salary model shows that
the 10 unit increase in individual on-base percentage costs $370,500 while the 10 unit increase in
individual slugging percentage costs $369,800 (Farrar & Bruggink, 2011). These results show
that for approximately the same increase in salary, an increase in on-base percentage brings in
11.1 more runs than the same increase in slugging percentage (Farrar & Bruggink, 2011). Even
years after the publication of Moneyball, on-base percentage continues to be undervalued, and
slugging percentage is overvalued. The moneyball hypothesis seems to have been accepted by
teams, baseball professionals, and fans throughout all of baseball. However, as these two studies
reveal, it is not fully implemented and utilized to its full potential. Today, employing only the
moneyball hypothesis does not give a team much of an edge over other teams as it did for the
Oakland Athletics in the late 1990s. There are many other strategies that small-market teams can
apply in order to compete with large-market teams with much higher payrolls.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
20
Utilizing the Farm System
An additional way small-market teams can build a competitive team despite their low
budget is to utilize the farm system and the annual draft. Every MLB team has minor league
team affiliates, typically consisting of at least a Class A team, a Class A-Advanced team, a
Double-A team, and a Triple-A Team. Select MLB teams also have Class-A Short Season
teams. Additionally, every team has at least two rookie teams (many teams have more than two).
The MLB First-Year Player Draft is held every year in June and all thirty Major League
Clubs participate. The teams take turns selecting players in reverse order of their win-loss
records at the close of the previous regular season. In other words, the team with the worst
record from the previous regular season selects the first player in the draft in the following year.
Additionally, the order is based off regular season records; the postseason has no effect on the
draft. Just because a team wins the World Series, it does not necessarily mean they pick last in
the draft.
When a team drafts a player, that club has full control over the player for at least three
full seasons. After these three seasons, a team must decide to place the player on the team’s 40-
man roster, meaning that the player has a major league contract, or the player becomes eligible
for the Rule 5 Draft
1
. Once a player signs a major league contract with a club, he does not
become eligible for free agency until he has at least six years of service time on a major league
team. Specifically, the player must have six years of service time on a major league 25-man
1
The Rule 5 Draft, held every December at the annual Winter Meetings, allows teams without a
full 40-man roster to select non-40-man roster players from other clubs (Major League Baseball,
2020b). It is organized similarly to the First-Year Player Draft as clubs draft in reverse order of
the standings from the previous regular season.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
21
roster or disabled list. Thanks to this, a club can essentially have control over players that they
draft for the first nine years of their careers, if the club decides to do so.
Trades
As demonstrated by Billy Beane in Moneyball, the key to making trades is playing off
other teams’ needs and hiding your own team’s desires. Teams need to know what they want,
and what they are willing to give up. The best trades occur when one team is desperate for a
certain player or desperate to decrease their payroll. Trades always involve at least two players,
but often times they include more than two players and sometimes cash. Though they are less
common, three-team trades also occur. One small-market team that successfully utilized trading
in recent years is the Tampa Bay Rays. On July 31, 2018, the Rays traded right-handed pitcher
Chris Archer to the Pittsburgh Pirates for right-handed pitcher Tyler Glasnow, rookie outfielder
Austin Meadows, and top pitching prospect Shane Baz. At the time, the Pirates were fighting for
the division title and decided to make the move before the Trade Deadline. In retrospect, the
Pirates ended in fourth in the division, did not make the playoffs, and lost a relief pitcher and two
incredibly promising young players. The Rays, however, turned Glasnow into a starting pitcher
and added a middle-of-the-order bat with Meadows. Then, in 2019, the Rays placed second in
the division clinching a spot in the postseason. The team went on to beat the Oakland Athletics
in the American League Wild Card game but lost the Division Series to the Houston Astros.
Making strategic trade decisions during the offseason, throughout the season, and before the July
31
st
Trade Deadline can be pivotal for a small-market team.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
22
Contract Negotiations
Contract negotiations are vital for small-market teams. Contract extensions are the most
common form of contract negotiations and are the form that small-market teams need to take
advantage of. After utilizing your farm system and bringing up young, talented players, teams
need to seize the opportunity to extend player contracts. Extending a player’s contract prevents
the player from reaching the free agent-pool. Krautmann (2016) finds that the vast majority of
contract extensions take the player beyond the point of free-agent eligibility. In free agency, he
can offer his talent to every major league team and take the highest bid, increasing his salary
tremendously and becoming too expensive for a small-market club. If the player enjoyed his
service time with the team, there is a good chance that he will agree to a contract extension rather
than enter free agency. Unlike in some leagues, MLB contracts are guaranteed, meaning that any
player who signs a major league contract is guaranteed the full amount of money promised by
those contracts. Players can sign a contract and never step foot on the field and still receive the
full amount of their contract. The main reason for this occurrence is injuries which players and
teams have little control over.
Arbitration. Along with contract negotiations comes arbitration. Players become
eligible for arbitration when they have three or more years of major league service but less than
six years of major league service and if they do not already have a contract for the next season.
Arbitration essentially means that if the team and the player cannot agree on a contract, the team
and the player each present a contract offer to an arbitrator, and the arbitrator chooses one
without compromising between the two. This puts both the player and the team at risk, but it is
much riskier for the team. The team’s offer is lower than what the player wants, so if a team
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
23
enters arbitration and loses, they are bound to the higher paying contract. However, arbitration
contracts are not guaranteed, as a club can release a player during Spring Training and be
responsible for only a prorated amount of their arbitration salary (Major League Baseball,
2020b). Releasing a player is one option for a team who lost the arbitration hearing and owe the
player more than they can afford. On the other hand, a player that has agreed to an arbitration
salary can break camp with the club and still be guaranteed his full salary (Major League
Baseball, 2020b). It would be best for small-market teams to avoid arbitration by negotiating
with the player and agreeing on a contract without the use of an arbitrator.
Long-term contracts. Avoiding long-term contracts is a simple way a team can prevent
themselves from wasting financial resources in the future. Signing players to long-term contracts
is typically attractive to a team because that means they have the security of having that player
on their roster for years to come. However, if a player gets injured, he is still entitled to his
entire contract. Therefore, a team would essentially be wasting all of the money on that player’s
contract and gaining nothing in return. Even further, players do not always perform as well in
future seasons as they did the season before signing the contract. Performance is not guaranteed
over an extended period of time. Take Chris Davis, for example. After leading the league in
home runs and putting up an OPS+ of 147
2
in 2015, Davis, who would be entering his age-30
season in 2016, signed a $161,000,000 seven-year contract. He has received and will receive a
base salary of $17 million each year from 2016 to 2022, and the remaining $42 million is
deferred from 2023 to 2037. This means that the Baltimore Orioles still owe him $51 million
2
OPS+ normalizes a player’s on-base plus slugging percentage across the entire league. A score
of 100 is league average, and a score of 150 is 50% better than the league average (Major League
Baseball, 2020a).
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
24
over the next three years as well as $42 million when he will not even be playing for them. After
his impressive 2015 season, his statistics got progressively worse over the next three seasons
with a slight improvement in the 2019 season. Even with the slight improvement, he still slashed
.179/.276/.326 with an OPS+ of 60 (Baseball Reference, 2020a).
Deferred salaries. Another way a team can utilize its financial resources to build a
competitive team despite a small budget is to take advantage of, but also be wary of, deferred
salaries. Deferring a player’s salary can sometimes be useful to a team when they have a higher
team payroll in the current year than what they are expecting in future years. For example, if a
team has a highly compensated player that will soon become a free agent but also want to sign
another player, they can defer the new player’s salary into future years where they will not have
the obligation to the impending free agent. Keep in mind that MLB teams must show that player
salaries that are deferred can be paid off in the next four years, even if the money is contractually
deferred beyond four years (Brown, Rascher, Nagel, & McEvoy, 2016). On the other hand, often
times, teams need to be wary of deferred salaries because teams often end up spending much
more on a player than expected or assumed. Take Bobby Bonilla for example. Bonilla received
his deferred salary from a buyout. Deferred money can come from a buyout or from contract
negotiations. In 2000, the Mets opted to pay Bonilla an annuity from 2011 to 2035 rather than
paying the salary they owed him that year. The Mets thought that the money they would save by
not paying Bonilla in 2000 would earn a higher return than the eight percent interest rate offered
to Bonilla (after considering the time value of money). Ultimately, Bonilla turned a $5.9 million
buyout into 25 yearly installments of $1.19 million.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
25
Performance incentive bonuses. Small-market teams should also consider including
bonuses in player contracts as incentives. Bonuses cannot be based on batting or pitching skill or
where the club finishes in the standings. However, a bonus can be based on number of days
spent on an MLB active list, number of games played, number of games started, number of
games finished, innings pitched for pitchers and/or number of plate appearances for position
players. Bonuses can also be based on awards such as MVP, Cy Young, Gold Glove, Silver
Slugger, and/or being named to an all-star team (Phil, 2012).
History of Successful Small-Market Teams
Although it has been challenging and rare for small-market teams to succeed in MLB,
some clubs have made it happen. Only one small-market team has won the World Series in the
last twenty years. The Florida Marlins had a payroll that ranked 25
th
out of 30 and did not even
win their division in the regular season, but ended up winning the World Series in 2003. Of their
top twelve players (based on WAR), two were acquired as free agents, two were drafted by the
club, and eight were acquired by trades (Baseball Reference, 2020b).
The Pittsburgh Pirates reached the postseason three years in a row from 2013 through
2015. In 2013, they had the fourth lowest payroll in the league but won the National League
Wild Card game and advanced to the Division Series. The club had the fourth lowest payroll
again in 2014, but they still managed to make it to the Wild Card game again, though they lost to
the San Francisco Giants who became the World Champions that year. In 2015, the Pirates had
the second-best record in the entire league for the regular season and appeared in the Wild Card
game for a third time.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
26
The 2015 Houston Astros and the 2019 Tampa Bay Rays had payrolls ranking 25
th
and
30
th
in the league, respectively, and won the American League Wild Card game but lost the
Division Series. The Oakland Athletics made it to the American League Wild Card game in
2018 as well as 2019 despite having the third lowest payroll in 2018 and the sixth lowest payroll
in 2019. The last example from recent years is the 2018 Milwaukee Brewers. The Brewers’
payroll ranked 22
nd
in the league, but the team won the NL Central Division title, and won the
Division Series, but lost the Championship Series.
Conclusion
Although some small-market teams are overcoming the inequality, the payroll disparity
and competitive imbalance among MLB teams is still highly evident today. There are a number
of ways that small-market teams can build a competitive team despite their low budget including,
but not limited to, employing the moneyball hypothesis, quantifying market inefficiencies,
utilizing the team’s farm system, taking advantage of trade opportunities, and making intelligent
contract decisions. Though the moneyball hypothesis is generally known throughout all of
MLB, large-market teams still tend to ignore its findings. Small-market teams can continue to
utilize this theory in order to build their team, but they must also implement other strategies as
well. Additionally, MLB should become more aware of the disparity that is still present in the
league and take steps toward reducing the inequality.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
27
References
Baseball Reference. (2020a). Chris Davis stats. Retrieved from https://www.baseball-
reference.com/players/d/davisch02.shtml
Baseball Reference. (2020b). 2003 Florida Marlins statistics. Retrieved
from https://www.baseball-reference.com/teams/FLA/2003.shtml
Baseball Reference. (2020c). Revenue sharing. Retrieved from
https://www.baseball-reference.com/bullpen/Revenue_sharing
Baumer, B. & Zimbalist, A. (2014). Quantifying market inefficiencies in the baseball players’
market. Eastern Economic Journal, 40(4), 488-498. doi:10.1057/eej.2013.43
Breunig, R., Garrett-Rumba, B., Jardin, M., & Rocaboy, Y. (2013). Wage dispersion and team
performance: a theoretical model and evidence from baseball. Applied Economics, 46(3),
271-281. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2013.839864
Brown, M. T., Rascher, D., Nagel, M. S., & McEvoy, C. D. (2016). Financial Management in
the Sport Industry, Second Edition. New York, NY: Rutledge.
The business of baseball. (2020). Retrieved from https://www.forbes.com/mlb-
valuations/list/#tab:overall
Farrar, A. & Bruggink, T. H. (2011). A new test of the moneyball hypothesis. The Sport Journal,
14(1). Retrieved from http://link.galegroup.com/apps/doc/A284323937/HRCA?u=vic_lib
erty&sid=HRCA&xid=0669e13e
Grow, N. (2016). The curiously confounding Curt Flood Act. Tulane Law Review, 90(4), 859
901. Retrieved from http://ezproxy.liberty.edu/login?url=http://search.ebscohost.com/
login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=115450031&site=ehost-live&scope=site.
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
28
Hakes, J. K. & Sauer, R. D. (2006). An economic evaluation of the moneyball hypothesis. The
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(3), 173-185. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.20.3.173
Hill, A. D., Aime, F., & Ridge, J. W. (2016). The performance implications of resource and pay
dispersion: The case of Major League Baseball. Strategic Management Journal, 38(9),
1935-1947. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2616
Hill, J. R. & Jolly, N. A. (2015). Revenue sharing and player salaries in Major League Baseball.
Journal of Sports Economics, 18(8), 831-849.
https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1527002515609660
Jolly, N. A. (2014). Revenue sharing and within-team payroll inequality in Major League
Baseball. Applied Economic Letters, 22(1), 80-85.
https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2014.927562
Krautmann, A. C. (2016). Contract extensions: The case of Major League Baseball. Journal of
Sports Economics, 19(3), 299-314. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1527002516656727
Krissoff, B. (2013). Society and baseball face rising income inequality. Spring 2013 Baseball
Research Journal. Retrieved from https://sabr.org/research/society-and-baseball-face-
rising-income-inequality
Langs, S. (2019). 2019’s highest paid player may surprise you. Retrieved from
https://www.mlb.com/news/highest-paid-baseball-players-in-2019
Lewis, M. (2003). Moneyball: The art of winning an unfair game. New York, NY: W. W.
Norton & Company.
Lu, X., Matthews, J., Wang, M., & Zhuang, H. (2018). Team payroll, pitcher and hitter payrolls,
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
29
and team performance: Evidence from the U.S. Major League Baseball. Economics &
Business Letters, 62-69. Retrieved from
http://ezproxy.liberty.edu/login?url=http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&
db=bth&AN=131283276&site=ehost-live&scope=site
MLB. (n.d.). 2017-2021 Basic agreement. Retrieved from
https://www.dol.gov/OLMS/regs/compliance/cba/2019/private/30MajorClubs_K9831_06
0122.pdf
Major League Baseball. (2020a). On-base plus slugging plus (OPS+)? Retrieved from
http://m.mlb.com/glossary/advanced-stats/on-base-plus-slugging-plus
Major League Baseball. (2020b). What is a guaranteed contract? Retrieved from
http://m.mlb.com/glossary/transactions/guaranteed-contract
Major League Baseball. (2020c). What is a rule 5 draft? Retrieved from
http://m.mlb.com/glossary/transactions/rule-5-draft
Phil, A. (2012). Performance incentive bonuses. The Cub Reporter. Retrieved from
https://www.thecubreporter.com/performance-incentive-bonuses
Rockerbie, D. & Easton, S. (2018). Revenue sharing in Major League Baseball: The moments
that meant so much. International Journal of Financial Studies, 6(3).
https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6030071
Shook, N. (2019). Salary cap expected to increase at least $8M in 2020. Retrieved January 27,
2020, from http://www.nfl.com/news/story/0ap3000001086709/article/salary-cap-
expected-to-increase-at-least-8m-in-2020
Tao, Y., Chuang, H., & Lin, E. (2016). Compensation and performance in Major League
PAYROLL DISPARITY AMONG MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL
30
Baseball: Evidence from salary dispersion and team performance. International Review
of Economics & Finance, 43, 151-159. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2015.10.037
USA Today. (2020). MLB salaries. Retrieved from
https://www.usatoday.com/sports/mlb/salaries/2019/team/all/